The Platformization of Labor and Society | Society and the Internet: How Networks of Information and Communication are Changing Our Lives | Oxford Academic
Skip to Main Content

Contents

The notion of the “platform” established itself in the tech industry in the early 2000s to designate digital intermediaries that match persons, information, and goods (Evans et al., 2006). The term, mainly borrowed from construction work, was initially synonymous with computer “architecture” (Hennessy and Patterson, 1990, Baldwin and Woodard, 2009). Thus, a platform can be mainly characterized as a software or hardware infrastructure on which users, companies, and even governments build applications, services, and communities.

In his book Platform Capitalism, Nick Srnicek (2017) distinguishes several types of platforms. Some run popular consumer services: advertising platformslike Google extract and analyze information from users and sell ad space; product platforms, like Spotify, transform goods into services accessible to subscribers; and lean platforms, like Airbnb, do not own the material assets from which they make profit. Other platforms cater exclusively to businesses: industrial platforms, like GE or Siemens, transform traditional manufacturing into Internet-based processes, while cloud platforms, like Amazon Web Services (AWS), rent data storage and computing power.

In light of the success of these services, platforms have established themselves as an organizational and technological paradigm both for tech industry companies and for companies, state and privately owned, that are not inherently technological, but whose business models transition toward platform-based strategies. For instance, insurance companies (such as Admiral), retail (such as Tesco), and transportation (such as French state-owned SNCF), are increasingly relying on platforms to coordinate and acquire data on their clients.

In this chapter we will focus on five aspects of the platformization phenomenon. First, the emergence of platforms as a replacement for preexisting modes of economic coordination. Second, the way platforms rely on data to create value. Third, how data is extracted from multitudes of users in the form of “digital labor.” Fourth, how users’ behavior is fragmented and reduced to standard tasks. And fifth, how trends toward “datafication” and “taskification” are the sinews of contemporary developments in automation and artificial intelligence.

Although platforms are grounded in digital technology, they primarily emerge as a response to long-term social and economic developments, particularly the diminishing relevance and efficiency of enterprises and markets, two traditional methods for organizing human productive activities.

Markets act as coordinating mechanisms, designed to enable several groups of buyers and sellers to interact. Conventionally, they achieve their goal using prices, thus matching individuals and organizations willing to provide a particular good or service in exchange for a certain amount of money (supply), with others who are willing to spend said amount (demand). Recent devastating crises that have hit both financial and goods markets have undermined collective confidence in their reliability as coordination mechanisms. Moreover, they have shown the limitations of prices in respect of adequately representing the values of the goods and services negotiated on the markets. Some commentators describe this situation as a “crisis in the representation of value” (Muniesa 2011: 33).

Anthropologist Jane I. Guyer (2016) argues that, by losing its relevance as a mechanism for coordinating human actions, the market has increasingly become “abstract” and disconnected from individual experiences. Previously depicted as a physical space where localized relationships occurred (“the marketplace”), the market has been increasingly reduced to an impersonal force governed by opaque rules that transcend individual comprehension (“the economy”) (Graeber, 2009). By contrast, platform components and applications present themselves as technological solutions with an actual impact on users’ lives. Especially when they take the shape of mobile applications, they are perceived as capable of offering concrete solutions to real-life problems: for instance by connecting individuals to friends and loved ones via Facebook or Tinder, by helping them beat traffic on Waze, or by providing them with tips on the best deals as in ShopSavvy or Trivago.

As markets detach themselves from individual experience, another perceived failure looms: that of traditional enterprises to create wealth and innovation. Between 1980 and 2000, in the wake of financial capitalism, established firms faced harsh global competition and progressively gave up their usual “retain and invest” models, based on the internalization of assets to develop innovative value-added services and products. Instead, they have opted for narrower “downsize and distribute” business strategies, where principles of lean management coexist with the massive outsourcing of labor and production processes to generate short-term profitability for their shareholders (Segrestin and Hatchuel, 2012). During the 2000s, for instance, US top businesses have sacrificed R&D programs by expending up to ninety-four percent of their revenue in stock-market manipulation, mainly buying back their shares to artificially increase their sales per share (Lazonick, 2010).

These tendencies have eroded the role of traditional enterprises as drivers of economic growth and have accelerated their replacement by the new platform-based social and technological paradigm. Instead of focusing on core competencies, business identity, and flagship products, digital platforms adopt a more dynamic (even opportunistic) approach. They act as meta-organizations that try to discard products in a pragmatic and sometimes volatile way (Ciborra, 1996). For example, Yahoo! has pivoted over time from being a directory of websites, to an email service, to a news portal. Before becoming a top microblogging platform, Twitter was a podcast delivery service. Also, Google has launched and then dispensed with several services, from the messaging software Google Wave to the wearable device Google Glass.

Another characteristic of enterprises is their reliance on hierarchies to curb transaction costs (Williamson, 1967). This strategy implies a sharp distinction between the inside and the outside of a firm: the former is regulated by hierarchies and subordination, while the latter is directed by the freedom to cooperate. Instead of complying with traditional companies’ “hierarchical control,” new platformed organizations blur the boundaries between the interior and exterior of a firm and are predicated on promises of horizontal coordination and independent access to material and informational resources. When they sign up on Etsy or eBay, for example, all users are assumed to participate on equal footing in the functioning of the platforms, none of them acting as a supervisor or a line manager. Furthermore, the terms they sign do not include exclusivity clauses that restrict their usages inside a single platform.

Despite that, a digital platform is less of a sharp departure from previous paradigms and more like a hybrid organization, halfway between a market and an enterprise. For instance, Amazon presents itself as a traditional enterprise, with a highly hierarchical structure that often manifests itself in a “bruising” work culture (Kantor and Streitfeldaug, 2015), and the reinvestment of financial gains into shareholders’ dividends. However, at the same time, it runs a thriving marketplace, where it connects sellers and buyers.

Like enterprises, platforms rely on intricate, multilayered, and ultimately hierarchical features (Gillespie, 2010). Like markets, they select goods, manage information, or even establish the prices of services. Uber’s surge pricing algorithm is emblematic of this: the overall number of users launching its app on their smartphones allows Uber to estimate the number of people who are “on the market” at a given time in a specific area. The platform operates on a just-in-time basis and, unlike taxi companies, it does not manage a stable fleet of vehicles or have access to reserved parking spaces. In order for that potential demand to turn into actual rides, enough cars must converge in the same neighborhood. To coordinate supply and demand, the price of a trip is not calculated from distance and other criteria, such as the time or the type of vehicle, but it is multiplied by a coefficient that can range from 1 to 50. Thus, Uber does not wait for passengers and drivers to come up with a price autonomously or to set a fixed price for its rides, but instead uses dynamic pricing (Hall, Kendrick, and Nosko, 2015). This example highlights another essential feature of digital platforms: they coordinate their components through algorithmic matching, rather than through simple price adjustment. Prices are not the results of free transactions between sides of a given market, since a real-time algorithmic arrangement sets them on the platform.

In the next section of this chapter, we will argue that algorithmic matching rests on the use of data to create value-added services. Data is, in turn, created by the ambiguously consented participation of its users.

The network structure of platforms enables them to appropriate the fruit of the activity of the multiple parties in each transaction, instead of extracting it from relations of productive subordination, as in the case of firms (Ryall, 2013). On the one side, platforms monetize their users’ interactions. Several, like Facebook or Google, make users’ information available to paying partners. Some, like Netflix, make their customers purchase a subscription to their services. Others take a percentage of the revenue that the users generate, as is the case with Amazon, whose fees can reach twenty percent of the price of a product sold in its catalog.

Most importantly, platforms capture value by collecting the output of their users’ participation. As tech investor and author Tim O’Reilly puts it: “The secret to the success of bellwethers like Google, Amazon, eBay, Craigslist, Wikipedia, Facebook, and Twitter is that each of these sites, in its own way, has learned to harness the power of its users to add value to…its offerings’ (O’Reilly, 2011: 13). One of the first mainstream search engines, Yahoo!, classified and referenced millions of websites according to categories established by multitudes of early service adopters. YouTube users produce, upload, rate videos, and even review them for inappropriate content so that the recommendation algorithm can make automated suggestions.

Value capture is a strategy the platforms have adopted since the dawn of the World Wide Web (Teece and Linden, 2017). User-generated content (or UGC) is one of the most visible forms of appropriation of user participation for commercial use. The major social media platforms of the 2000s (Friendster, Myspace, YouTube, and Facebook in Western countries and Orkut, QQ, Sina Weibo, and VKontakte in emerging ones) owe their success to billions of “volunteer” users that over the years have produced their text, images, sounds, and videos.

However, user-generated content is not the only source of value for digital platforms. Value capture means that any information provided by the users represents a commercial advantage. Such information can also be attached to the products and services that circulate on a platform: ratings, engagement statistics, and commentaries help discriminate among sellers on e-commerce websites or service providers on ride-hailing apps.

Moreover, the harvesting of data and metadata has been a primary source of user-related value for tech companies. Data can be described as any information about the users requested by the platforms or volunteered by the individuals: a name, a telephone number, a password, but also the likes’ on a specific content and the messages in someone’s inbox. Metadata is information about other data: for instance, a tag on an Instagram picture, the IP address attached to a Wikipedia edit, or the description under a YouTube video.

This information is continuously monetized: sold or made accessible for a fee to brands and advertising networks, to other businesses, and even to governments for the surveillance of their population. Despite their marketing and communications strategies, platforms insist on the technical aspects of their success (their algorithms, their servers, or their drones), and their ability to extract contents, data, and metadata from their users is paramount. Their growth does not depend on a single product or service, but on the overall value that they can extract from the personal data they possess, the dynamism of their communities, and the relevance of the services they offer. In the following section we analyze how, by stimulating user participation, platforms end up creating a new form of inconspicuous digital labor.

The capture of material and immaterial resources generated by communities of users can be considered either as a form of participation and “co-creation” or as a way of putting users to work to turn their participation into “digital labor” (Scholz, 2012). In a landmark publication, Tiziana Terranova describes digital labor as the “free labor on the net” and lists activities falling under this description as “building Web sites, modifying software packages, reading and participating in mailing lists, and building virtual spaces” (2000: 33). Beyond this initial characterization, as we have discussed, digital labor cannot be limited to a pro bono production of content, since activities performed by users, from filling in their profiles to drawing up a friend list, represent lucrative opportunities for tech giants.

In a practical sense, what digital labor encompasses is not confined to free Internet labor, but embodies a range of nonstandard forms of production, from semi-professional amateurism to monetized leisure, and from unpaid click-work to “gigs” and freelancing. This type of labor relations, mediated by digital platforms, locates productive activities outside of regular employment and spawns a variety of invisible or informal working arrangements which do not guarantee fundamental rights such as paid leave, retirement, safety, and most importantly, the right to be paid for one’s contribution.

On social media, the production of information conventionally manifests itself in unpaid activities performed by users, so that online services can profit from every social media post, every gaming session, every comment, every photo uploaded, in so far as “both social media and the factory are products of capitalism and are, ultimately, adapted to its purposes” (Rey, 2012: 401). This, of course, creates tensions with formal labor markets and exerts a pressure on professionals and specialized service providers.

One of the early experiments in digital labor on Facebook was Diaries, a 2007 TV series made up of montages of user-generated videos. Around it, Facebook developed a fruitful broadcast partnership with Comcast (Johnston, 2007). The series served as advertising as well as a revenue source from the broadcasting rights. In the context of the reduction of the workforce in the media industry, according to Nicole Cohen (2008), the recourse to amateur content amounts to the outsourcing of content production to online multitudes of producer-consumers. This informal labor is so entangled with actual labor that it is redefining labor markets and eroding workfare protections, thereby prompting the emergence of new occupational identities built upon precarity and risk-taking.

Thus, the exclusive focus on free labor gives way to new evidence showing that digital labor is a continuum of unpaid, micro-paid, and poorly paid human activities, thus encompassing the kind of actions performed by users of participatory media as well as platform-based piecework (Casilli, 2017).

The example of on-demand platforms such as Uber, TaskRabbit, Deliveroo, or Airbnb is emblematic: based on mobile apps allocating material and informational resources in real time, they connect customers with independent goods or service providers. These platforms act as algorithmic matchmakers between one group of users (riders, home-owners, customers, or guests) and those who secure transportation, maintenance, catering, or accommodation. On-demand apps are incredibly dependent on material human labor, whether direct (a category of users performing physical tasks such as driving, delivering, or cleaning) or indirect (a category of users affording an asset like an apartment, a car, or a piece of equipment). Yet, this material labor is deeply interconnected to the information economy platforms thrive upon. Users are pressured not only to provide services, but also to create content, data, and metadata. For instance, Airbnb encourages its members to participate beyond the hospitality service. It acts as a social media platform, where both hosts and guests have to upload volumes of photos, texts, messages, and evaluations. Users also have to provide geolocation data or socio-demographic information (such as their name, address, or age). To satisfy its data needs, Airbnb has partnered with other platforms, for instance with Foursquare to employ its geolocated images in its city guides (Garun, 2016).

In order to generate data and to allow algorithmic matching of different groups of individuals, platforms encourage the “taskification” of work, or the reduction of human activities to the smallest conceivable unit of execution (virtually, a click), to facilitate interconnection and value capture. Platforms operate in ecosystems where consumers (e.g., those buying flights and booking hotels on Expedia), interact with companies (like hotels or airlines), smaller platforms (such as those which run ads and sponsored links on websites and mobile), or public infrastructures (e.g., airline schedules databases). All these individuals and organizations are components of the platform, and they all have to perform interoperable actions. The reduction of human activity to normalized and simplified elements is necessary for platforms to coordinate and access an ecosystem composed of individuals, communities, apps, and databases.

The standardization and the fragmentation of previously complex and specialized processes are essential to run a platform ecosystem where the activities of users fit in and are synchronized with others (Gray, 2016). Twitter, for example, is a medium that employs short of 3,860 people worldwide, as of 2018, has no actual editorial staff, and entrusts its users with the responsibility of producing and circulating content. The extreme standardization of its service, the publication of messages of less than 280 characters, has allowed its growth from 0 to 335 million accounts over the span of twelve years since its inception in 2006. By outsourcing mostly fragmented and effortless tasks of content selection and enrichment to its users (likes, retweets, and hashtags), the platform can efficiently run existing accounts, and easily add new ones.

Despite apparent similarities, the platform-based “taskification” represents a departure from the twentieth-century Taylorism in which the ideal of industrial-era scientific management sought to normalize work in units of time in order to reduce the internal complexity of the factory. The diversity of individual contributions (like different crafting styles or quality standards) was better integrated into the collective effort to produce value internally. In contrast, platform-based tasks are mainly connected to outsourcing, which becomes their prevalent way of operating. As far as platforms tend not to produce internally the goods and services they provide, their added-value tasks are fragmented and performed by their ecosystem of users. Nevertheless, it is a new type of outsourcing that takes place on platforms: it is not an individual or an organization that becomes a subcontractor, but an entire network, multitudes of production units, all qualified as users.

Furthermore, the Taylorist strengthening of bureaucracies and the simplification of labor processes were designed to develop critical skills within a company’s workforce. Platforms, by contrast, bring forth a new division of labor which ensures a high level of productivity by involving users, consumers, and freelance workers in the production. Those who perform tasks are not specialized professionals with an obligation to achieve results, but casual, disposable, and virtually low-skilled performers that may not even require a small amount of pay. Standardization and segmentation of labor processes are thus instrumental in facing the uncertainty that this new division of labor entails.

A final consequence of platformization is the use of taskified labor to shape up business automation processes. Since platforms reduce labor to tasks—and sometimes to micro-tasks—a vast amount of data and metadata increasingly fuels human-based computation. This technique allows machines to crowdsource simple operations like tagging, flagging, or adding content descriptions to human users.

Maybe the best-known platform specialized in micro-tasks is Mechanical Turk, a service created by Amazon in the mid-2000s to provide services such as data refinement and enrichment, image recognition, and speech-to-text. Its users are classified as “consumers-workers,” and are usually paid as little as one or two cents to perform tasks that vary in complexity (Hara et al., 2018).

Half-jokingly, the service was launched by Jeff Bezos (2006) as a way to produce “artificial artificial intelligence.” In other words, automation performed by crowds of human users. Indeed, artificial intelligence should ideally execute the HITs (Human Intelligence Tasks) performed by Mechanical Turk workers. Nevertheless, too often, machine-learning models lag beyond the commercial claims of their producers and their investors (Irani, 2015). Despite the promises of “full automation,” human digital labor compensates for the technical limitations of new intelligent solutions supposed to automate business processes. More broadly, the execution of micro-tasks is necessary to “train” artificial intelligence (i.e., to calibrate machine-learning models by providing them with millions of examples of human judgments, choices, and behaviors). To make automation possible, digital platforms recruit hundreds of millions of human beings as users, customers, participants, and, in some cases, cheap micro-workers.

The relationship between platforms, taskified digital labor, and automation can be better appreciated if we consider that, despite exaggerated claims by platform owners about a foreseeable “strong AI” capable of simulating all human cognitive processes (Kurzweil, 2010), present-day artificial intelligence is generally “narrow AI” based on “shallow” statistical learning methods (Hayes, 2012). Apart from its application in manufacturing technologies (the “smart factory”) where it is used to advance preexisting automated physical processes of production, the most visible manifestations of this “narrow” AI are represented by late-2010s “virtual assistants.” Voice-activated systems such as Siri, Alexa, or Cortana can be found both in smartphones and in smart speakers. These mainstream devices popularize the use of applications, websites, and services that require machine-learning methods to execute complex actions: to suggest and play music, to make a dinner reservation, or to switch off the lights to save energy. They purportedly operate without human intervention. Nevertheless, the autonomy of these systems needs to be measured against the need for human labor to correct and sort through users’ requests. Armies of silent listeners and transcribers are hired every day to double-check the responses provided by virtual assistants or to compare human transcripts and computer recordings of the sentences uttered by users.

Facebook even tried to turn the concealed humans executing tasks that should be performed by machines into a selling point. In 2015, the Palo Alto giant launched “M,” a text-based virtual assistant which was described as a “supercharged AI powered by humans” (Metz, 2015). Although these humans were supposed to supervise the actual machine learning for a limited amount of time, three years later they still performed up to seventy percent of the tasks (Griffith and Simonite, 2018), a testament to the fact that full automation and human-level artificial intelligence are far from being the “manifest destiny” of contemporary digital technologies (Feigenbaum, 2003).

Evaluators, “data wranglers,” and human assistants for the virtual ones are recruited by and for platforms (Lenke, 2016) and put to work in increasingly precarious working conditions. In some cases, they perform piecework on portals such as Mechanical Turk, UHRS, and RaterHub—which provide the tech giants Amazon, Microsoft, and Google with micro-tasks and data, respectively. In other cases, they are paid on an hourly basis by global subcontracting platforms like Appen, Lionbridge, and Pactera.

However, the vast majority of tasks are performed pro bono by unpaid platform users. This is attested by the success of systems such as ReCAPTCHA which, under the pretext of detecting bots, has been duping users into “training” optical character reader software deployed to transcribe Google Books (Von Ahn et al., 2008) and more recently to train autonomous cars and sometimes military AI. Harvesting users’ clicks and enacting concealed micro-tasks to sustain machine-learning solutions is a common strategy that Alphabet has been profitably using to enhance everything, from Google Search to Google Translator.

Present-day incarnations of artificial intelligence are thus heavily dependent on “non-artificial” work to operate. Despite the common argument that “machines are stealing our jobs,” AIs are not replacing human beings, considering that they need them to exist and to overcome their limitations. In domains as diverse as healthcare, management, and leisure, machines cannot effectively learn unless they interact with platform users who correct their mistakes, reduce their bias, interpret their information, and perform actions in their place.

In so far as present-day AI systems are conditioned by computing power, big data, and financial resources provided by digital platforms, they depend on the digital labor performed by their users, who complete the tasks that make machines “intelligent.” They create new technological assemblages which externalize labor processes, thus turning previously paid services into “unpaid consumption work” (Huws, 2003). From this point of view, AI does not represent a continuation of early industrial labor-saving technologies like the spinning mules or the locomotives, but is a close relative to more recent technologies, like the self-checkout machines and ATMs (Palm, 2015). As in the cases of customer-activated and often semi-attended terminals, automation does not replace work but displaces it to an increasing number of unpaid workers or “non-workers,” for example, operators misrepresented and misclassified as workers of a lesser kind (micro-workers, temps, contingent, precarious, non-specialized data workers, and content providers). Platforms are the technological and organizational mechanisms that allow this task allocation to take place—and this brand of shallow automation to pursue its course.

In this chapter, we have presented five aspects of the adoption of the platform paradigm in society, and its consequences regarding business and market organization, labor and automation. The societal implications of platformization will continue to unfold in the near future. While the outcomes are uncertain, it seems clear that there is a need to address the grievances and distortions that digital platforms generate.

Despite being often described as “technologically neutral,” platforms are political in nature. One of the senses of the word “platform” is precisely that of a set of principles constituting a blueprint for future policies (e.g., the “platform” of a party or of a candidate). Digital platforms should be reconciled with this original meaning, so that they assume the social responsibilities appropriate to their impact on society.

This implies that platforms cease to disguise the political decisions their owners and investors make every day (about what kind of information circulates, who gets the biggest share of the value they capture, whose rights and welfare are guaranteed) as the impartial workings of ever-accurate algorithms. In a sense, there is no algorithm—it’s only somebody’s decision. Thus, it comes as no surprise that one of the fiercest battles taking place today around platforms is to oblige them to be transparent, auditable, even “loyal” to their users. These principles are now debated, advocated, and (in some European countries) enshrined in law (Sandvig et al., 2014; Gillespie, 2018; French Official Journal, 2016).

Recognizing the political nature of platforms also means conceding that their privately owned, capital-driven model is far from being the only existing one. Public platforms exist and prosper, ranging from state-owned ones (see, for example, the controversial Indian biometric and demographic data platform, Aadhaar) to those operating at both local and regional levels (see the cities partnering in the European Commission’s Urban Data Platform). More promisingly, community-based or cooperative platforms are emerging all over the world. Some are embedded in the larger movement for the “digital commons” and try to recreate a sense of belonging and participation, beyond the commercial logics that regulate capitalist platforms. Others converge toward a distinctive brand of “platform cooperativism” (Scholz, 2016), based on collective ownership and governance of digital infrastructures. Principles of mutualism and solidarity can thus be coupled with platformization, especially to establish fairer working conditions and to limit the competition among “digital laborers” on platform-mediated tasks (Graham and Woodcock, 2018).

Baldwin, C. Y. and Woodard, C. J. (

2009
). “The Architecture of Platforms: A Unified View,” in A. Gawer (ed.),
Platforms, Markets and Innovation
. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, 19–44.

Bezos, J. (2006). “Opening Keynote and Keynote Interview.” MIT World—special events and lectures, September 27. Available at http://techtv.mit.edu/videos/16180-opening-keynote-and-keynote-interview-with-jeff-bezos. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Casilli, A. A. (

2017
). “
Digital Labor Studies Go Global: Towards a ‘Digital Decolonial Turn,
’”
International Journal of Communication
, 11(1): 3934–54.

Ciborra, C. U. (

1996
). “
The Platform Organization: Recombining Strategies, Structures, and Surprises,
Organization Science
, 7(2): 103–18.

Cohen, N. (

2008
). “
The Valorization of Surveillance: Towards a Political Economy of Facebook,
Democratic Communiqué
, 22(1): 5–22.

Evans, D. S., Hagiu, A., and Schmalensee, R. (

2006
).
Invisible Engines. How Software Platforms Drive Innovation and Transform Industries
. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Feigenbaum, Edward A. (

2003
). “
Some Challenges and Grand Challenges for Computational Intelligence,
Journal of the ACM
, 50(1): 32–40.

French Official Journal (

2016
). Law No. 2016–1321, October 7. “
For a Digital Republic.

Garun, N. (

2016
). “Airbnb Will Now Use Foursquare Photos in its City Guides,”
The Verge,
December 7. Available at www.theverge.com/2016/12/7/13869010/airbnb-buys-foursquare-photos-city-guides. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Gillespie, T. L. (

2010
). “The Politics of ‘Platforms,’”
New Media & Society
, 12(3): 347–64.

Gillespie, T. (

2018
). Custodians of the Internet Platforms, Content Moderation, and the Hidden Decisions That Shape Social Media. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Graeber, D. (

2009
). “Debt, Violence, and Impersonal Markets: Polanyian Meditations,” in C. Hann and K. Hart (eds),
Market and Society: The Great Transformation Today
. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 106–32.

Graham, M. and Woodcock, J. (

2018
). “
Towards a Fairer Platform Economy: Introducing the Fairwork Foundation,
Alternate Routes
, 29(1): 242–53.

Gray, M. L. (

2016
). “
Your Job Is About to Get ‘Taskified.
’”
Los Angeles Times
, January 8. Available at www.latimes.com/opinion/op-ed/la-oe-0110-digital-turk-work-20160110-story.html.

Griffith, E. and Simonite, T. (

2018
). “
Facebook’s Virtual Assistant M Is Dead. So Are Chatbots.
Wired
, August 1 (Business). Available at www.wired.com/story/facebooks-virtual-assistant-m-is-dead-so-are-chatbots/. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Guyer, J. I. (

2016
).
Legacies, Logics, Logistics: Essays in the Anthropology of the Platform Economy
. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Hall, J., Kendrick, C., and Nosko, C. (

2015
). “The Effects of Uber’s Surge Pricing: A Case Study.” Paper presented at the workshop
Designing the Digital Economy
, Cambridge, MA, Microsoft Research New England, October 24–25. Available at http://1g1uem2nc4jy1gzhn943ro0gz50.wpengine.netdna-cdn.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/01/effects_of_ubers_surge_pricing.pdf. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Hara, K., Adams, A., Milland, K., Savage, S., Callison-Burch, C., and Bigham, J. (

2018
). “A Data-Driven Analysis of Workers’ Earnings on Amazon Mechanical Turk,” in
Proceedings of the 2018 CHI Conference on Human Factors in Computing Systems
, 1–14. April 21–26. Montreal QC, Canada.

Hayes, B. (

2012
). “
The Manifest Destiny of Artificial Intelligence,
American Scientist
, 100(4): 282–7.

Hennessy, J. L. and Patterson, D. A. (

1990
).
Computer Architecture: A Quantitative Approach
. New York: Elsevier.

Huws, U. (

2003
).
The Making of a Cybertariat: Virtual Work in a Real World
. New York: Monthly Review Press.

Irani, L. (

2015
). “
The Cultural Work of Microwork,
New Media & Society, 14(1): 137–52.

Johnston, G. (

2007
). “
Comcast Site Teams with Facebook,
Broadcasting & Cable, 137(7): 16.

Kantor, J. and Streitfeldaug, D. (

2015
). “
Inside Amazon: Wrestling Big Ideas in a Bruising Workplace.
New York Times
, August 15. Available at www.nytimes.com/2015/08/16/technology/inside-amazon-wrestling-big-ideas-in-a-bruising-workplace.html. (Accessed March 21, 2019).

Kurzweil, R. (

2010
).
The Singularity is Near: When Humans Transcend Biology
. New York: Penguin.

Lazonick, W. (

2010
). “
Marketization, Globalization, Financialization: The Fragility of the US Economy in an Era of Global Change.
2010 BHC Meeting, Athens, Georgia
, March 27. Available at http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.628.1345&rep=rep1&type=pdf. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Lenke, N. (

2016
). “
Part 1 – AI for Customer Care: Human Assisted Virtual Agents Get Smart with Big Knowledge
”.
Nuance—In the Labs
. Available at http://whatsnext.nuance.com/in-the-labs/human-assisted-virtual-agents-machine-learning-improve-customer-experience/. (Accessed September 11, 2018).

Metz, C. (

2015
). “
Facebook’s Human-Powered Assistant May Just Supercharge AI.
Wired
, June 29. Available at www.wired.com/2015/08/how-facebook-m-works/. (Accessed November 3, 2018).

Muniesa, F. (

2011
). “
A Flank Movement in the Understanding of Valuation,
Sociological Review
, 59(2), 24–38.

O’Reilly, T. (

2011
). “
Government as a Platform,
Innovations: Technology, Governance, Globalization
, 6(1): 13–40.

Palm, M. (

2015
). “The Costs of Paying, or Three Histories of Swiping,” in O. Frayssé and M. O’Neil (eds),
Digital Labour and Prosumer Capitalism
: The US Matrix, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 51–65.

Rey, P. J. (

2012
). “
Alienation, Exploitation, and Social Media,
American Behavioral Scientist
, 56(4): 399–420.

Ryall, M. (

2013
). “
The New Dynamics of Competition,
Harvard Business Review
, 91(6): 80–7.

Sandvig, C., Hamilton, K., Karahalios, K., and Langbort, C. (

2014
). “
Auditing Algorithms: Research Methods for Detecting Discrimination on Internet Platforms.
” Paper presented to “Data and Discrimination: Converting Critical Concerns into Productive Inquiry,” preconference at the 64th Annual Meeting of the International Communication Association, May 22, Seattle, WA, US.

Scholz, T. (ed.) (

2012
).
Digital Labor: The Internet as Playground and Factory
. New York: Routledge.

Scholz, T. (

2016
).
Platform Cooperativism: Challenging the Corporate Sharing Economy
. New York: Rosa Luxemburg Stiftung.

Segrestin, B. and Hatchuel, A. (

2012
).
Refonder l’entreprise
, Paris: Éditions du Seuil.

Srnicek, N. (

2017
).
Platform Capitalism
. Cambridge: Polity Press.

Teece, D. J. and Linden, G. (

2017
). “
Business Models, Value Capture, and the Digital Enterprise,
Journal of Organization Design
, 6(8): 1–14. Available at https://jorgdesign.springeropen.com/track/pdf/10.1186/s41469-017-0018-x. (Accessed March 21, 2019).

Terranova, T. (

2000
). “
Free Labor: Producing Culture for the Digital Economy,
Social Text, 18(2): 33–58.

Von Ahn, L., Maurer, B., McMillen, C., Abraham, D., and Blum, M. (

2008
). “
reCAPTCHA: Human-Based Character Recognition via Web Security Measures,
Science
, 321(5895): 1465–8.

Williamson, O. E. (

1967
). “
Hierarchical Control and Optimum Firm Size,
Journal of Political Economy,
75(2): 123–38.

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

Close

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

View Article Abstract & Purchase Options

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

Close